Innovation in the Public Sector

I. Introduction

For the last 30 years, relentless technological innovation has seemingly conquered most, if not all, corners of the world. While the focus was on infrastructure and social networks in its early stages, the latest phase has set its eyes on core productive and financial processes that will undoubtedly have a profound socio-economic and environmental impact across the board. Rapidly adapting to the emerging global context is the clarion call for most countries to remain relevant and competitive at the international level.

Many developing countries find themselves in a unique situation. For starters, most innovations and technologies hold a foreign passport and thus need to first travel and then be adopted and adapted to the national context. Having local capacities  – human, financial and institutional – to achieve such a goal is a tacit requirement that many poorer nations lack off hand.

Also, given relatively scarce fiscal and human resources, this group of nations must prioritize investments in innovation and technology to accelerate the achievement of established national and international development goals and targets. Finally, developing countries should also strengthen national innovation systems (NIS) that, in the medium-run, could help create much-needed capacities not only to absorb external innovations and technologies but also to incubate and develop local ones that could end up having global relevance and application.

In this equation, governments can play both a critical and catalytic role. First, governments should develop and put into action relevant policies that foster science, technology and innovation (STI) and the ubiquitous deployment of digital technologies, as suggested by SDG 9. Second, governments should ensure that the provision of public goods and services, directly under their purview, scales up and reaches the whole population. And third, governments should facilitate the provision of private goods and services by promoting the development and operation of the private sector.

The last two are part of SDG 16 that openly acknowledges that governments in the Global South face myriad institutional gaps that impede the agile adoption or development of innovations and technologies and, by implication, the achievement of core development targets. That many also have limited fiscal capacity and are facing prolonged periods of slow growth adds insult to injury – not to forget that many are still struggling to cover all geographical points adequately within their national boundaries.

In this context, institutional capacity has two different hats. It is a means to harness and foster innovations and technology. On the other hand, it is also a development goal as adequate levels should be in place to wear the first hat properly. Developing countries must find the right balance between the two to ensure institutional capacity is in the running from the onset. As technology and innovation, institutional capacity is dynamic, a moving target jogging together and several others.

Indeed, most developing countries are no strangers to the deployment of innovative digital technologies. In fact, several could be seen as pioneers within the entire cohort of countries. Many have endorsed policies and launched a plethora of initiatives related to ICTs, Digital Government and innovation.

Progress, however, has been slower than expected. The provision of public goods is still in its infancy, thanks to a weak state and institutional capacity. The age of fiscal austerity complicated matters. Being that as it may, the core challenge in most, if not all, technology and innovation policies and initiatives is the failure to link the areas to state capacity and institutional development. Many innovation guides that have popped up all over the place in the last five years assume a level playing field in this regard. In this view, institutional capacity is perceived as an exogenous factor and one that technology and innovation cannot seem to impact.

II. Framework

Innovation, Technology and Change

In principle, technological innovation is a subset of overall innovation. That means that not all innovation occurs thanks to technological change. While this might have been the case until the end of the last century, new digital technologies’ global and cross-sectoral pervasiveness is changing such a perspective.

Digital technologies are usually part of most innovation processes in three ways: 1. As infrastructure via digital networks and cloud computing, for example. 2. As a means of information, communication and data sharing via social media, big data, and data analytics, partly thanks to mobile technologies. And 3. As a digital platform or application such as mobile apps, blockchain technology and Artificial Intelligence. The latter is best known as digital innovation. Nowadays, most innovations use digital technologies in one or more of the three ways described above.

In this note, innovation is defined accordingly and is thus almost always linked to new digital technologies.

In the standard innovation approach, governments have two distinct roles in the innovation process. First, they should lead innovation processes within the public sector to augment efficiency, effectiveness, responsiveness and transparency. Second, governments should create an adequate policy environment to promote private sector-led innovation and let the market drive the overall process. While the two are seemingly connected, the mainstream view argues that the latter is the prime mover in the whole process. Thus, governments should only intervene in the case of so-called “market failures.”

However, recent research strongly suggests that the issue is unclear-cut as government innovation policies can also target specific sectors or priority areas, as discussed below.

State Capacity and Political Regimes

History shows that epochs of rapid technological innovation and change are accompanied by critical structural changes at the institutional and organizational levels in both the public and private sectors. Technology innovation is usually running well ahead of institutional development that is almost always playing catch up. At the same time, the same evidence pinpoints that accelerated technical change can initially affect the population in the short term. It thus demands special attention to tackle emerging or resurgent socio-economic and political gaps.

State capacity is thus an essential component. While no consensus exists on a single definition, for the purposes of this note, state capacity comprises three interrelated pillars:

  1. Institutional capacity. Capacity to design and implement policies and programs to deliver public goods, the legal capacity to sustain the rule of law, and the existence of a professional and capable civil service.
  2. Fiscal capacity. Capacity to capture and manage financial resources sustainably via taxation and alternative sources, including external ones (FDI, ODI). Administrative capacity is a key feature here.
  3. Infrastructural capacity. The capacity to undertake institutional and fiscal activities throughout the territories under state control, including the protection of all citizens.

From an institutional and governance perspective, distinguishing between state capacity and political regimes is essential. Strong states are frequently perceived as proxies for authoritarian or non-democratic regimes. However, most Western democracies have developed high-capacity states, a process that has taken over 100 years. On the other hand, many non-democratic regimes have to juggle with low-capacity states and use force as the primary and only means to sustain social cohesion. Table 1 below depicts the relationship between state capacity and political regimes.

Table 1: State Capacity and Political Regimes

Differentiating state capacity from political regimes is thus critical. 

Policy and Administrative Capacity, and Institutional Design

In terms of innovation processes and technology adoption throughout, policy capacity takes center stage. Policy capacity boils down to making informed policy choices from a variety of options. These choices hopefully will end up promoting sustainable development while facilitating the strategic deployment of new technologies. This process should not be limited to the public sector alone, by default. Instead, it can also explore public-private interactions and specific mission-oriented ventures to enhance or accelerate overall human development.

Policy capacity is inextricably linked to administrative capacity, the latter being the capacity to capture, manage and efficiently disburse the necessary fiscal and financial resources to support any given set of policy choices. Administrative capacity can be a wake-up call for policy agendas if the options made by decision-makers are exceedingly ambitious in terms of financial resources and existing capacities. On the other hand, making policy decisions that are not tightly linked to fiscal capacity will either delay or stop implementation altogether. Thus, policymakers should always tightly link policy and administrative capacities. Unfortunately, many developing countries exhibit a wide rift between these two sets of interrelated capacities – when available.

Both policy and administrative capacities will impact the shape institutional development will take and, thus, on overall state capacity. On the one hand, a given level of institutional development can limit the implementation of chosen policy agendas. On the other hand, policy agendas can also opt for a particular type of institutional development, centralized or decentralized. In all cases, policy agendas within a given set of administrative capacities will impact public sector institutions, evolving over time accordingly.

III. Innovation and State Capacity

Overview

Innovations within the public sector are linked to digital transformation and public sector reform efforts to change and modernize public institutions and their internal organizational structure. Here, the process starts with developing relevant innovation policies that can trigger institutional innovation and sustain it in the long run. These two components are thus closely associated.

Two models that explain how innovation occurs in the public sector are available. The first one highlights the existence of an efficient and knowledgeable bureaucracy that operates with relative autonomy and has links to the private sector. In this model, centralized institutions are critical and enable public sector innovators to access funds, human resources and key policymakers.

The second model centers on entrepreneurship and charismatic individuals who can easily open doors and thus access resources and key decision-makers. In this model, a decentralized organization is the primary driver of public sector innovation. This model is also regularly used to distill innovation processes in the private sector, which usually emphasizes the individual’s role.

Nevertheless, note that both models assume that a given level of institutional capacity is already in place and thus provides fertile ground to kick-start innovation processes. That is undoubtedly a strong assumption in many developing countries where such capacity is still incipient. Furthermore, neither model directly links innovation to enhancing institutional capacity and thus has little to say in state capacity and its components. But, again, that is a critical link that developing countries need to factor to embrace comprehensive innovation policies that can increase in one way or another institutional capacity – which in turn pushes forward the achievement of fundamental development goals.

Innovation Paths

In many developing countries, strengthening policy and administrative capacity and institutional organization is necessary to implement innovation and technology policy agendas effectively. However, losing sight of these close interconnections during the policy-making process creates insurmountable challenges that cannot be bypassed otherwise.

Recent research has identified two generic paths developing countries adopt to promote innovation and technology adoption processes to foster inclusive economic growth. Table 2 below summarizes these findings.

Table 2: Innovation Development Paths

Policy agenda Domestic centered, building national capacities Foreign focus, attracting foreign resources to build national capabilities
Administrative/ Financial focus  Domestic savings as core source, strong incentives to local private sector FDI as key source, competition as trickle-down mechanism
Institutional organization Centralized bureaucracies with high expertise and close links to the business community Specialized autonomous entities working independently following a private sector model

The domestic route was taken in the 1980s by East Asian countries such as Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan. The national state was the prime mover of the process and used innovation and technology to drive change. That led to the emergence of the developmental state concept, where public sector-led policy innovations have a pervasive impact throughout the economy. Contrary to standard policy recommendations by IFIs at the time, these countries found a new way to promote inclusive growth and enhance human development. Nowadays, these countries are core players in the world economy and have by now transferred out of the developing country global team.

After 1989, most Eastern European countries opted for the foreign-led path and had an unbounded commitment to the potential benefits of globalization, financial services included. However, while a few are performing relatively well, most are now facing increased inequality and institutional development seems to have stagnated. In any event, none of these countries has been as successful as any of the so-called Asian Tigers.

The opening shot in the path selection process is decisive and offers a stark choice between foreign and domestic options. Countries facing stagnant economic growth, low domestic savings and high corruption will undoubtedly have less liberty to select an optimal path. In any event, the initial path selection of the overall policy agenda will profoundly impact administrative and financial arrangements and shape the institutional organization and overall state capacity development accordingly.

Nevertheless, nothing stops developing countries from starting with the foreign-led path in the short-term and then switching to the domestic route in the medium or long term. That, in fact, seems the path China has taken. However, such a switch will demand additional financial resources, a certain level of policy and administrative capacity and a sophisticated institutional organization structure to sustain the effort.

Innovation and the State

As mentioned before, the traditional approach argues that governments and the state, in general, play a passive role in innovation processes limited to setting policies and promoting the business sector. However, the historical evidence strongly suggests the picture is much more complicated.

In the late 1950s, the U.S. government created the Advanced Research Projects Agency (ARPA) in response to the surprise launch of Sputnik by the Soviets. ARPA was conceived as an independent R&D agency leading the country in technology research, primarily focusing on global military superiority. ARPA, renamed to DARPA in 1972 (D standing for defense), brought together government, academia and the private sector to foster innovation and develop leading-edge technologies. Perhaps one of the most known outcomes of ARPA was ARPANet, the precursor of today’s Internet. The protocols that sustain the global network of networks were developed under the auspices of ARPA/DARPA.

As ARPANet grew over the years, the academic and non-military components of the network were ceded to the National Science Foundation (NSF) in 1990. NSF is yet another example of a state-funded R&D agency searching for leading-edge technologies and solutions. Not surprisingly, research funded by the NSF supported the creation of the various technologies that allowed Apple to integrate them under the concept of the iPhone, for example. Not surprisingly, the UK has recently announced it will be creating its own ARPA-like entity.

The developmental state of the East Asian countries furnishes another example, but this time within the context of development. This set of countries created independent entities staffed with top-of-the-line talent, expertise and knowledge that drove policy choices while keeping the private sector full on board. The core idea was to develop domestic capacities at all levels to compete with industrialized countries in the global market. The evidence today shows that they were indeed successful – acknowledging that geopolitics at the time played a crucial role.

Note that both examples also showcase the relevance of the domestic-center innovation path. In any case, governments have a role to play in fostering innovation processes to tackle their core developmental challenges, such as the SDGs. They must be willing to take risks while working together with the private sector and the universities. Institutionally, driving innovation within government and across all of society demands the creation of new independent entities agile enough to explore and prototype innovations. This should be complemented by having sufficient institutional capacity to implement large-scale innovations while securing the required financing.

Cheers, Raúl

 

Selected References

Acemoglu, Daron, Camilo García-Jimeno, and James A. Robinson. 2015. “State Capacity and Economic Development: A Network Approach.” The American Economic Review; Nashville 105 (8): 2364–2409. http://dx.doi.org.ezproxy.unal.edu.co/10.1257/aer.20140044.

Arocena, Rodrigo, and Judith Sutz. 2000. “Looking at National Systems of Innovation from the South.” Industry and Innovation 7 (1): 55–75. https://doi.org/10/b49b93.

Bardhan, Pranab. 2016. “State and Development: The Need for a Reappraisal of the Current Literature.” Journal of Economic Literature 54 (3): 862–92. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20151239.

Bartels, Frank L., Hinrich Voss, Suman Lederer, and Christopher Bachtrog. 2012. “Determinants of National Innovation Systems: Policy Implications for Developing Countries.” Innovation 14 (1): 2–18. https://doi.org/10/gd4qw6.

Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson. 2009. “The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights, Taxation, and Politics.” American Economic Review 99 (4): 1218–44. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.4.1218.

———. 2010. “State Capacity, Conflict, and Development.” Econometrica 78 (1): 1–34. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA8073.

Fagerberg, Jan, Bengt-Åke Lundvall, and Martin Srholec. 2018. “Global Value Chains, National Innovation Systems and Economic Development.” The European Journal of Development Research 30 (3): 533–56. https://doi.org/10/gd8xqm.

Fagerberg, Jan. 2017. “Innovation Policy: Rationales, Lessons and Challenges.” Journal of Economic Surveys 31 (2): 497–512. https://doi.org/10/f9r8g8.

Freeman, Chris. 1995. “The ‘National System of Innovation’ in Historical Perspective.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 19 (1): 5–24. https://doi.org/10/gdk2vr.

Godin, Benoît. 2009. “National Innovation System: The System Approach in Historical Perspective.” Science, Technology, & Human Values, February. https://doi.org/10/bxzqcs.

Haggard, Stephan. 2004. “Institutions and Growth in East Asia.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38 (4): 53–81. https://doi.org/10/dpsp3j.

Hau, Matthias vom. 2012. “State Capacity and Inclusive Development: New Challenges and Directions.” esid-002-12. Global Development Institute Working Paper Series. GDI, The University of Manchester. https://ideas.repec.org/p/bwp/bwppap/esid-002-12.html.

Hendrix, Cullen S. 2010. “Measuring State Capacity: Theoretical and Empirical Implications for the Study of Civil Conflict.” Journal of Peace Research 47 (3): 273–85. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343310361838.

Karo, Erkki, and Rainer Kattel. 2014. “Public Management, Policy Capacity, Innovation and Development.” Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 34 (1): 80–102. https://doi.org/10/gghfwr.

———. 2016. “How to Organize for Innovation: Entrepreneurial State and Organizational Variety.” 66. The Other Canon Foundation and Tallinn University of Technology Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics. TUT Ragnar Nurkse Department of Innovation and Governance. https://ideas.repec.org/p/tth/wpaper/66.html.

Lember, Veiko, Rainer Kattel, and Piret Tõnurist. 2018. “Technological Capacity in the Public Sector: The Case of Estonia.” International Review of Administrative Sciences 84 (2): 214–30. https://doi.org/10/gd89qg.

Litwak, Eugene, and Josefina Figueira. 1968. “Technological Innovation and Theoretical Functions of Primary Groups and Bureaucratic Structures.” American Journal of Sociology 73 (4): 468–81. https://doi.org/10/ft85b6.

Lundvall, Bengt-Åke. 2007. “National Innovation Systems—Analytical Concept and Development Tool.” Industry and Innovation 14 (1): 95–119. https://doi.org/10/c4srdj.

Mazzucato, Mariana. 2018. “Mission-Oriented Innovation Policies: Challenges and Opportunities.” Industrial and Corporate Change 27 (5): 803–15. https://doi.org/10/gfdbxb.

_______ 2016. “From Market Fixing to Market-Creating: A New Framework for Innovation Policy.” Industry and Innovation 23 (2): 140–56. https://doi.org/10/gfc7ps.

Mazzucato, Mariana, and Gregor Semieniuk. 2017. “Public Financing of Innovation: New Questions.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 33 (1): 24–48. https://doi.org/10/f97n8b.

Muralidharan, Karthik, Paul Niehaus, and Sandip Sukhtankar. 2016. “Building State Capacity: Evidence from Biometric Smartcards in India.” The American Economic Review 106 (10): 2895–2929. http://www.jstor.org/stable/43956939.

Savoia, Antonio, and Kunal Sen. 2015. “Measurement, Evolution, Determinants, and Consequences of State Capacity: A Review of Recent Research.” Journal of Economic Surveys 29 (3): 441–58. https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12065.

Seidel, Uwe, Lysann Müller, Gerd Meier zu Köcker, and Guajarino de Araújo Filho. 2013. “A New Approach for Analysing National Innovation Systems in Emerging and Developing Countries.” Industry and Higher Education 27 (4): 279–85. https://doi.org/10/gd4qxf.

Tilly, Charles. 2007a. Democracy. Cambridge, [England] ; New York: Cambridge University Press.

———. 2007b. “Grudging Consent.” The American Interest; Washington, September 2007. http://search.proquest.com/central/docview/224657912/abstract/5D96F3565D974606PQ/1.

Tõnurist, Piret, Rainer Kattel, and Veiko Lember. 2017. “Innovation Labs in the Public Sector: What They Are and What They Do?” Public Management Review 19 (10): 1455–79. https://doi.org/10/gfz64t.

UCL. 2019a. “A Framework for Mission-Oriented Innovation Policy Roadmapping for the SDGs.” UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose. June 25, 2019. https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/publications/2019/jun/framework-mission-oriented-innovation-policy-roadmapping-sdgs.

———. 2019b. “Innovation Bureaucracies: How Agile Stability Creates the Entrepreneurial State.” UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose. December 20, 2019. https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/publications/2019/dec/innovation-bureaucracies-how-agile-stability-creates-entrepreneurial-state.

Vries, Hanna De, Victor Bekkers, and Lars Tummers. 2016. “Innovation in the Public Sector: A Systematic Review and Future Research Agenda.” Public Administration 94 (1): 146–66. https://doi.org/10/gc5rs6.

Yeung, Henry Wai-chung. 2014. “Governing the Market in a Globalizing Era: Developmental States, Global Production Networks and Inter-Firm Dynamics in East Asia.” Review of International Political Economy 21 (1): 70–101. https://doi.org/10/gghjht.

Zambrano, Raúl. 2008. “E-Governance and Development: Service Delivery to Empower the Poor.” International Journal of Electronic Government Research; Hershey 4 (2): 1–11. http://dx.doi.org.ezproxy.unal.edu.co/10.4018/jegr.2008040101.

________. 2020. “Taming the Beast: Harnessing Blockchains in Developing Country Governments.” Frontiers in Blockchain 2. https://doi.org/10.3389/fbloc.2019.00027.

Zambrano, Raúl, and Simone Eymann. 2014. “Crowdsourcing and Human Development: The Role of Governments.” In Proceedings of the 8th International Conference on Theory and Practice of Electronic Governance, 170–177. ICEGOV ’14. New York, NY, USA: ACM. https://doi.org/10.1145/2691195.2691223.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email